Posted by Dr Christian Hilber, SERC and LSE
I recently
participated in a public debate organized by the Strategic Society Centre. The topic of the debate was the government’s Help to Buy scheme. The central question: Who will benefit from the scheme? My
short answer: It is almost certainly not the young first-time buyers who
are the supposed main beneficiaries of the scheme.
How
can this be? Aren’t the equity loan scheme and the mortgage guarantee
scheme directly targeted towards first-time buyers? Yes, true. And does
the equity loan scheme not only apply to new build homes? Again, yes,
true. It is true that Help to Buy will likely increase mortgage
availability, especially for those attempting to buy with small
deposits.
However, the effect of this is an increase in demand for
housing – in economics language: it shifts the individual and aggregate
demand curves outwards to the right. It does not shift the supply
curve. But as long as supply is ‘responsive’ (i.e., the supply curve is
not very steep), this should still have the desired effect of more new
housing and perhaps only slightly higher prices.
So what can we say about the supply side? In the very short-run,
housing supply does of course not respond at all to demand shocks
because of planning and construction lags, so prices can be expected to
rise in the short-run. The trouble is that in the UK, even in the very long-run, supply
is incredibly unresponsive to demand shocks (i.e., the long-run supply
curve is very steep). Why? The main culprit is the UK planning system,
which is, in an international context, extraordinarily inflexible.
Since 1947 there are virtually no fiscal incentives at the local level
to permit development. Local planning authorities face most of the
costs of development but have very few benefits from it. Moreover,
local homeowners – in the UK perhaps best described as BANANAs (Build
Absolutely Nothing Anywhere Near Anything) – oppose (virtually) any
development in their backyards.
As a consequence of all
this, Help to Buy will likely have the effect of pushing up house
prices (and rents) further with very little positive effect on new
construction. Housing will likely become less – not more – affordable
for young would-be-owners! The beneficiaries of the scheme are the
existing (typically wealthier) homeowners who benefit from the capital
gain. However, not all homeowners benefit equally. Young expanding
families may not benefit at all since their new larger house will also
become more expensive. The true beneficiaries are those elderly
homeowners who are thinking about downsizing (not many) and those
wealthier retired homeowners who decide to pocket the capital gains
from Help to Buy and move to Spain or Southern France, where housing is
much more affordable and spacious. First-time buyers will arguably be
no better off because the easier access to credit is offset by higher
prices. And mobile young households who do not want to or still cannot
own will be worse off. They will face higher rents and, as tax payers,
bear the burden of the schemes.
The empirical evidence strongly supports these arguments. In recent work (here and here) Wouter
Vermeulen and I provide strong evidence that local planning
constraints – in conjunction with strong local demand – are indeed the
main culprit of the extraordinarily high house prices and the cramped
spaces in the Greater London Area and the South East of England. (The
UK has the second highest house prices per square metre in the world – only topped by tiny Monaco – and new build houses in the UK are 38% smaller than in densely populated Germany and 40% smaller than in the even more densely populated Netherlands.)
In another paper, forthcoming at the Review of Economics and Statistics,
Tracy Turner and I find for the US, that in tightly regulated cities
mortgage rate subsidies have the effect of substantially raising house
prices and reducing homeownership attainment – the opposite of
policy makers’ intentions. The aggregate effect on homeownership
attainment for the US as a whole is ‘zero’. Notably, this is achieved at
an annual cost exceeding $100 billion.
Proponents of
Help to Buy have argued that the equity loan scheme only applies to new
build homes, so this should only increase the demand for new build
homes and thus lead to more construction. But this is a bogus argument:
existing homes and new build homes (and in fact rental homes) are
reasonably close substitutes, so Help to Buy will affect aggregate
demand for housing and not just new build. There have been, at long
last, clear signs of a recovery in the construction sector – in fact,
for a while now; talk to architects! But this has nothing to do with
Help to Buy. It is merely a (welcome) coincidence (for proponents of
the scheme).
I argued above that the main beneficiaries are mainly
wealthy and older homeowners. But especially the wealthy arguably also
pay much of the taxes. So one might think that Help to Buy does ‘no
good’ but it also does ‘no harm’ – it is a ‘zero sum
game’. Unfortunately, this couldn’t be further from the truth for at
least two important reasons. Firstly, the taxes needed to finance the
schemes have a ‘dead weight loss’ – they are a pure welfare loss to the
society. Secondly, there are ‘systemic risks’. In contrast to, for
example, the American and Canadian systems, there is no cushion in the
form of private mortgage insurance companies that bear the risks
associated with a house price bust.
In the US for
example, even before the crisis, Fannie Mae and Freddie Mac only
guaranteed and securitised mortgages up to a 80% loan-to-value (LTV)
ratio; the portion of the loan that exceeded 80% of the house value had
to be ‘enhanced’ by private mortgage insurance companies. These
insurance companies either assumed those risks or – more likely –
reinsured them, the reason why AIG got into such trouble. Should the
British housing market(s) take a significant hit (perhaps not very
likely, but who would have predicted the ‘Great Recession’?), then the
situation for UK taxpayers would be much worse than that of US
taxpayers.
This is because the government doesn't just provide an
implicit warranty as a last resort (as was the case in the
US) but directly takes the first hit. Private mortgage insurance companies won't provide any cushion, unlike with Fannie and
Freddie (who only got into trouble because house prices in many metro
areas decreased by more than 20%). The UK government – or rather, the
British tax payer – will face huge costs, even if loans go only slightly
‘under water’. The fact that mortgages in the UK are ‘recourse’ helps
in the sense that there would be fewer defaults (compared to the US
mess) but would also arguably mean prolonging the crisis.
A
last point: what is the exit strategy? If the scheme was indeed
withdrawn abruptly after three years, then might this not cause a house
price bust and yet quite possibly another recession. If this is ‘too
big a political risk’, is it really plausible to think that the scheme
will end in three years? My concern really is that we end up in a
vicious circle with a policy that arguably does not only do more harm
than good and is very costly but is also very hard to get rid of. If we
are lucky, the two schemes will, for whatever reason, never really
take off and the schemes will be silently discarded after a few years.
My sincere hope is that the government does more to tackle the real
problem on the supply side: the fact that there are too few incentives
at the local level to permit residential (or commercial) development. I
floated the idea of a genuine local property tax that would replace
the current council tax and stamp duty (another harmful tax – see here and here) …it would be a (good) start…
A version of this post first appeared on the LSE Politics and Policy blog.