[Posted by Prof Henry G. Overman]
Following the Queen's speech my twitter feed is full of people expressing views for or against devolution to cities. Supporters push for maximum devolution to boost growth and productivity, improve efficiency in local government and build the northern powerhouse. Critics suggest the main attractions lie elsewhere - for example as a means of cutting government expenditure, a crude power grab by local politicians and a way for Londoner's to reduce taxes.
While there may be some truth in both these arguments, they won't do much to progress debate on what might constitute the right balance of powers between central and local governments. Indeed, what's a little depressing, but not very surprising, is the extent to which the vociferous public debate appears to pay almost no regard to the large academic literature that considers this issue.
Here, for example, is Wallace E. Oates one of the leading experts on fiscal federalism writing in a 1999 Journal of Economic Literature essay:
"But the proper goal of restructuring the public sector cannot simply be decentralisation. The public sector [...] consists of several different levels. The basic issue is one of aligning responsibilities and fiscal instruments with the proper level of government. [...] To realize [the advantages of federalism] we need to understand which functions and instruments are best centralized and which are best placed in the sphere of decentralized levels of government"
I've reflected on some of these issues before on this blog. For example, I'm pretty convinced that many decisions on transport and housing would better sit below national but above local authority level. After all, the evidence suggests that this is the spatial scale at which labour and housing markets operate. The governments proposals on metro mayors would help achieve this improved alignment.
In contrast, I'm still to be convinced on skills policy. Local authorities are certainly clamouring for powers in this area. But I worry that there is too much focus on higher level skills and not enough on the basics. I personally think the evidence is clear that early years and schooling should be central to any LED policy. Not only do these policies directly target one of the central problems faced by poorer families, but good local schools also help attract and retain already educated workers. But, I have no idea whether skills policy needs to be individualised, localised or centralised. I have similar reservations when it comes to active labour market policy.
I'm pretty sceptical on local industrial policy (e.g. cluster policy, complex attempts to
create innovation systems, targeting particular sectors etc) because I
don't think the evidence on its effectiveness is compelling and I worry that competition amongst local areas will lead to wasteful - and ultimately fruitless - expenditure.
Finally - I don't have a strong view on health or policing - because these are areas in which I have no particular expertise.
This isn't supposed to be comprehensive list - and my position on some of these areas isn't settled. Convincing evidence could shift my opinion either way. But we need the debate to shift from arguments over 'whether' to arguments over 'what' and 'why'. To my mind, we need answers to these latter two questions, before we can figure out how to proceed.
Thursday, 28 May 2015
Friday, 22 May 2015
Are they Green *Belts* by Accident?
Posted by Paul Cheshire, LSE and SERC
We Brits are a self-satisfied lot, and seem to
assume that Green Belts are a splendid British invention and a wonderful boon
to the world. A signal of our praiseworthy efforts to protect the green:
whether the village green or the environment: never a signal of our nostalgic
hankerings for a rural England which never existed.
In fact, the truth seems remote from this English
foundational myth. The way in which Green Belts developed suggests they are
only belts by accident and are
certainly an imported idea. As part of the work for a London First report, I have
recently been looking at how our Green Belts came into existence and how their
purposes have been transformed in the process. It is an extraordinary story, and
I have learnt substantially from Jonathan Manns' work.
*
In the 19th Century, many continental
European cities were getting rid of their city walls: the development of the
nation-state and mechanised warfare had rendered them functionally irrelevant.
This was happening in Vienna in the late 1850s and the idea of a Ringstrasse park was proposed. Although
Napoleon had twice shown that Vienna’s fortifications could not withstand a
modern (early 19th Century) army, the conservative Austrian military
withstood their demolition until 1857. The city walls
had had an area around them kept clear for military purposes, so their
demolition released a substantial circular ring of space around the city. Bourgeoisie
civic-mindedness was just developing. The map shows what was proposed: a Green
Belt if ever there was one! But only a belt by accident. It was on the space
released by the city walls and not surprisingly city walls had a roughly
circular shape.
In the UK we also tend to link the idea of
green belts to Ebenezer Howard’s proposals for Garden Cities. Not so. The first British
person to propose a Green Belt seems to have been Lord Meath – an Anglo-Irish
public figure and philanthropist. He is an interesting character and, to put it
mildly, very alien to modern sensibilities. Despite being an Alderman on the original LCC he believed in the
fundamentally corrupting nature of cities – so far as possible, their size
should be limited and rural-urban migration halted. He also believed cities ‘corrupted’
the gene pool of the British. He realised, however, that London was going to
continue to grow: so his answer was to increase the supply of green spaces and
recreation grounds in London and construct a ‘Green belt or girdle’. His other
solution to the burgeoning urban population was state-sponsored emigration to
the British Colonies: he was a strong Imperialist - indeed the founder of
Empire Day, a public holiday to celebrate the British Empire wherever the sun
never set.
Meath explicitly imported the idea from the
Viennese proposal but his version of a green belt or girdle had much more in
common with Howard’s later ideas for green belts around his Garden Cities of Tomorrow than it did
with the modern Green Belt. Apart from the Viennese Ringstrasse park, Meath was influenced by his visits to the US and
seeing early ‘beltways’ – wide avenues around major cities. He envisaged such a broad avenue connecting
public open spaces, some existing and some to be bought and dedicated to public
use, encircling London.
An updating of his proposal as published in 1901 is
illustrated below (and is taken from here). Much of the Meathian green belt was close to central London
and all would have been within the GLA boundaries – mostly inside the inner
boundaries of the modern Green Belt.
Source: Aalen, F. Planning Perspectives, 1989
The idea was taken up by the London Society in1919 in its proposed Development Plan for Greater London. This was still a
proposal for ‘green lungs’ for a smoky, dirty and highly congested London.
Official adaptation came in 1935 when the old London County Council endorsed
the idea. It was implemented in 1938 with the Green Belt (London and Home
Counties) Act. This empowered
local authorities to buy land for public use. By the late 1940s 20,000
hectares of land had been bought around London dedicated as public open space.
In the immediate post-WWII period of
reconstruction under the Atlee government, Green Belts were provided for all
major cities that wanted them under the Town and Country Planning Act of 1947. But
this did not propose buying land. The Act – still the basis for our planning
system - expropriated ‘development rights’ from freehold land ownership. So in
effect it gave power to local governments to prevent urban development on as
yet undeveloped land. It did not give rights of public access or generate any
change in ownership. Privately-owned land, if designated as Green Belt, would
remain private. So, while still promoted in the name of green space, in
practice the Green Belt provisions in the 1947 Act just stopped anything happening
– rather than creating valued recreational or open spaces.
Although the 1947 Act provided for Green Belts,
however, it did not implement them. That the 1947 Act was a creation of the
Atlee government gives the Labour Party a sense of ownership of the idea but
the implementation was under a Conservative Housing Minister, Duncan Sandys, in
1955. And the purposes by now had totally changed – both in aspiration and in
reality. No more were Green Belts to be green lungs or recreational space; they
were just to stop development.
As the Minister wrote: “even
if…neither green nor particularly attractive scenically, the major function of
the Greenbelt was…to stop further urban development”. That
remains their function as confirmed in the National Planning Policy Framework of 2012. Their purpose was to be empty spaces
between cities, to protect the Home Counties from the encroachment of London
and force urban expansion to jump over Surrey or Hertfordshire to Northants,
Cambridgeshire or Hampshire.
*
In the early 20th
Century the Californians tried to apply zoning to confine Chinese minorities to
particular neighbourhoods and later, in Louisville, Kentucky, zoning ordinances
were brought in to stop Blacks from buying houses in certain areas. This was
deliberate discriminatory zoning designed to protect privileges and create new
ghettoes. Such discriminatory zoning was struck down by the Supreme Court in
1917, but the right to zone in a non-discriminatory way was permitted in a
judgement of 1926. Local communities in the US soon found a way of keeping
‘undesirables’ out: they zoned for single family homes only and on large plots.
Over time plots became ever larger and what is now euphemistically known as
‘minimum lot size’ requirements became pervasive.
It is claimed, for example,
that ‘the Bay Area is built-out’. And so it is in the sense that more or less
all available zoned lots are developed. But look across the Golden Gate Bridge
and you see Marin County just a mile or so from downtown San Francisco. Minimum
lot sizes in many of the communities in Marin County are 60 acres! There are
many prosperous communities in the mid-West and West of the US which have 10,
20 and even 50 acre minimum lot size requirements. This is very effective at
keeping poor people out. It is exclusionary but is does not discriminate and so
is legal. It also contributes significantly to the sprawl of US urban development.
*
Greenbelts, as implemented, have become
a very British form of exclusionary zoning. They have the effect of confining the urban poor to
live at high densities in the cities and preserving the Home Counties (and
other similar green places near to all our other cities with Green Belts of
their own) for the aspirant gentry who had got there earlier on the tracks of
the suburban railway network; or as bohemian urban refugees establishing
artistic colonies such as Eric Gill’s Piggotts or the Sussex retreats of the Bloomsbury Group. It seems to be a long-standing tradition of the privileged
British to want to deny for others what they enjoy themselves. Particularly if
they can do so while maintaining a stance of moral superiority, presenting
themselves as protectors of the real interests of those whose desires they
frustrate. Prominent members of the Bloomsbury Group, happily housed in
England’s pleasant fields, were solid supporters of the early Council for the Preservation
of the Rural England and J. M. Keynes contributed to Clough Williams-Ellis’s
seminal 1928 anti-urban tract, Englandand the Octopus. Williams-Ellis himself, of course, built a tasteful
Italianate Disneyland precursor on a beautiful estuary in North Wales. But he
had taste so that, of course, was alright.
Thus the idea of Green Belts, the
accidental innovation – aimed at adding green space to high-density ancient
Vienna in place of the city walls, then adopted in unaltered form in England as
an idea to improve urban life for all – has been transmuted into a protective
device for the wealthy. If you really want to plan to protect and provide
better access to green space and open countryside without artificially constraining
land supply and forcing up house prices, then Green Fingers (or Green Wedges)
would seem to be the best solution. That is what more egalitarian Scandinavians
have. Copenhagen has its Green Fingers – really brown urbanisation along the radial routes out of
the city with protected countryside each side. Denmark has not just got cheaper
housing: according to the Dallas Fed’s data, the real house price has increased by a factor of 1.6 in
Denmark compared to 3.4 in the UK since 1975 but new houses in Denmark are a
lot bigger: 80% bigger in fact.
Now green wedges seem like a quite
sensible idea.
Monday, 27 April 2015
A real housing crisis, but only fake solutions
Posted
by Paul Cheshire, SERC and LSE
All the
Party manifestos are published now. All agree there is a housing crisis. The
most recent data for housing starts in England show a fall of 19% in the last
quarter of 2014 compared to the post-2008 high or the 2nd quarter of
2014; and completions and planning applications have been flat-lining since
2009. The latest English Housing Survey showed a
continuing rise in age for first time buyers and that the proportion of 25 to
34 year olds who were owner occupiers had fallen from 59 to 36% over 10 years;
and for the first time ever, more owner occupiers did not have mortgages than
did. In other words all the evidence shows that house building is not
significantly rising from what was a 100-year peacetime low in 2010, that the
supply and affordability crisis continues – even gets worse – and the redistribution
of housing wealth to the elderly continues.
A CentrePiece article last year
explained that there had been a shortfall of building during the past 20 years
of between 1.6 to 2.3 million and far too many of the houses that had been
built were in the wrong places or the wrong type to satisfy demand. But – even
worse – that the crisis was self-inflicted by longstanding policies.
Now we
have Alice in Wonderland proposals: solutions that require us to believe six
impossible things before breakfast and that words mean exactly what the
manifestos say - not what they really mean. This will not build houses. Nor
will promising to build 200,000 new houses a year (Labour), 230,000 starter homes
(Conservative) or – any advance on 200,000? Yes, 300,000 a year (Lib Dem).
Targets
and promises do not build houses. The experience of London demonstrates this.
Since 2004 housing targets for London have risen from less than 20,000 to
42,000. There was a slight upturn in actual building in the boom conditions of
2004/05 to 24,000. Since then, as targets have risen, so building has fallen.
In 2013/14 completions dipped to less than 18,000.
To build houses one has to have land to put them on, a realistic diagnosis of
the underlying causes and mechanisms for delivering them. Just raising targets
or promising more houses simply means a larger shortfall between promise and
delivery and an ever increasing unaffordability of housing.
Because
the problem is the supply side. Urban containment boundaries were set in 1955
and the area of greenbelt has greatly expanded since then. London’s is now more
than 3 times the area of the GLA (and 22% of the GLA is Green Belt); Oxford’s
Green Belt is more than 7 times the area of Oxford. Oxford is now the least affordable city
for housing in the UK and the City is surrounded by CPRE hotbeds telling
them they cannot build here! It is very difficult to build upwards because of
planning controls and every proposal to develop becomes an exhausting struggle
because each decision is politicised by our mechanism of ‘development control’.
Countries which do it more sensibly have plans and what the plan and building
regulations permit, can be built.
*
Of the
political manifestos perhaps the Tories’ is the most shameless. Senior
Conservatives are not economically illiterate so they really know better. But
what they are promising is more demand boosting: not only help to buy but
extending the right to buy to houses no government owns; even major property agencies have condemned
this proposal. Then the wheeze is to build 200,000 ‘Starter Homes’ to be
sold to under-40 first time buyers at a 20% discount (from what?); and a London
Land Commission to magically find tracts of Brownfield land that have
presumably been hiding behind railway embankments for the past 15 years; and
more powers to Local Authorities to resist building on the Green Belt. The
Starter Homes, the small print reveals, will be either at the expense of
‘affordable’ housing built as part of planning deals or at the expense of
‘unviable’ commercial development. So not much net new construction there.
One can
be entirely confident that the Conservative proposals will do nothing to
increase the number of houses built net. This means their proposals will make
housing even less affordable because they will subsidise demand but not
increase supply. UKIP’s proposals are even less helpful. But then fair enough:
one should expect less of UKIP in terms of sensible policies designed to tackle
real problems. UKIP want to revise the 2012 National Planning Policy Framework
(no evidence this has increased house building but it does offer some slight
hope) to make it more difficult to build, increase the extent of Green Belts
and extend the right to buy; but to British Nationals only.
Both
the Lib Dems and Labour are, amongst other things proposing to build more
houses. The trouble is neither really explains how it can be done nor sets out
practical mechanisms to do it. So essentially they offer acts of faith. The Lib
Dems propose 10 new Garden Cities on a revived Oxford-Cambridge rail link. But
apart from some general statements about capturing land value uplift to pay for
infrastructure, no mechanism is proposed for getting round the entrenched
powers of opposition the current planning system provides anyone who opposes
building.
Their
other proposals either boost demand without adding to supply (Help to Rent) or
have an old fashioned whiff of anti-landlordism and anti-speculator mindsets.
They propose giving even more power to local communities to determine
development. Without radical complementary changes to taxation, a new system to
guarantee new houses come with additional infrastructure and losses are
properly compensated this will strengthen the power of NIMBYism even more. A
problem of just local decision making is that it empowers those who bear the
costs of development (real – noise and dirt during construction, loss of views
and more congestion – in the absence of new infrastructure – after the new
houses are built) but disenfranchises those who stand to benefit – would–be
residents or owners. The Lib Dem proposal to pilot land value taxation is
potentially helpful but another proposal - to make planning decisions even more
complex by inventing conditions requiring occupation after construction - is
not. How on earth could that be imposed? Suppose the market turns down
unexpectedly or the developer just gets the local market wrong? It will add yet
more risk to the development process so cause otherwise viable projects to slip
from viability.
Labour
did have the foresight to commission the Lyons Review of Housing but their
manifesto conveys the impression they almost wish they had not. They promise to
increase house building to 200,000 a year by 2020 but there is no mention of
how to increase land supply or funding renewed public sector house building.
Instead there is coverage of what seems like an ill-thought out proposal to
re-channel finance from Help to Buy ISAs; how to stop ‘land banking’ and
‘speculation’ by introducing ‘use it or lose’ planning permission and double
taxation on empty homes. Then there is a proposal to tighten controls on
landlords by mandating 3-year tenancies and a national register of private
landlords. The most explicit proposal on the supply side is to ‘start to build
a new generation of garden cities’. But while Lyons was explicit with details
and delivery mechanisms, the manifesto is not. Similarly the Lyons Review had
an informed analysis of the underlying problem – our self-imposed shortage of
development land; the difficulty of getting across boundary agreements (see the Oxford case) and how over
simplistic is the idea of relying on Brownfield land. There is no mention of
these serious points in the Labour manifesto.
*
Overall,
the manifestos confirm that all parties are unwilling to face up to the
political problems they perceive would follow if they advocated solutions that might effectively address
the crisis of housing supply. The illness is real but all that is on offer
is snake oil; displacement activities treating some symptoms but not the
underlying causes and – paradoxically - having the net effect of making the
crisis worse. Perhaps that is just a little harsh on Labour but I did just hear
their spokesperson offering the party’s solutions and the whole emphasis was on
how the ‘market was not working so the planning system needed to be tougher’.
Not so: the problem IS the planning system. It needs root and branch reform but
that would take serious political courage. Fake solutions will not work: in the
case of many of those on offer, including discouraging landlords, making an
already mind-boggling planning system yet tougher and more complex or boosting
demand when the problem is supply, the crisis will get worse. Indeed the
housing crisis will get worse anyway without radical reform of the planning
system, and local taxes and property taxes; and incentives.
This
post originally appeared on the LSE British
Politics and Policy blog.
Friday, 24 April 2015
What is good architecture worth?
Posted
by Gabriel Ahlfeldt & Paul Cheshire, SERC and LSE
Economists, unlike cynics, do not know
the price of everything – not by a long way. Certainly we do not know the price
of good architecture. Apart from anything else identifying ‘good architecture’
is highly subjective. So to measure its price you have to make some brave
assumptions about what it is and where to find it. And from an economic
perspective the price is not the interesting issue. The interesting issue is: left
to their own devices, would markets under or over provide ‘good architecture’? In
the jargon, is there a problem of market failure?
For sure, public policy in this area implicitly
assumes that there is market failure, and that markets alone will not provide
enough good architecture. For example, policymakers intervene to control the
design of new buildings, and to stop private owners from altering or replacing
existing ones. But this has costs: both directly in administration and
compliance, and indirectly through impacts on energy costs, on usable space in
cities and on economic outcomes. A series of papers from SERC researchers explores
these economic effects in detail.
Regulation for good design may lead to
rent-seeking behaviour: Cheshire and Derricks find evidence that
developers use ‘Trophy Architects’ to game the planning system, as a way to get
more space on a given site. This study – like some others – identifies
‘good architecture’ by classifying buildings as high quality if they are
designed by architects who had already won a major lifetime achievement award:
‘Trophy Architects’ or ‘Starchitects’. Such awards go back a long way, so there are
19th Century buildings in London which qualify.
Cheshire and Derricks find that for commercial
buildings, a Trophy Architect (TA) adds no premium at all to the price of
buildings. But it does add to both the design and construction costs: with TA
design, the cost per m2 for a 25-floor building is 10 to 17.5% higher. TA
design also seems to make buildings slower to let out, which suggests there
could be a rental premium, even though there is no increase in a building’s
selling price.
There is a puzzle here. TA design adds nothing
to a building’s selling price, implying no productivity benefit from
starchitecture. So why do developers pay a premium for construction? The answer
appears to be that using a Trophy Architect helps game the regulatory system. Controlling
for other factors, in London such buildings were an astonishing 19 floors
higher than buildings on similar sites designed by ordinary architects.
An economist would say that the developers were
using design to generate ‘rents’. In a city with tight planning rules and
development controls, the extra rentable space in these big buildings implies a
130% increase in the value of a typical site on which there was a possibility
of building tall. The problem is that these rents become a deadweight loss as
the extra cost of using a trophy architect, the extra time through the planning
system, and the extra risk of eventually not being successful absorb potential
gains.
In London, some 25% of skyscrapers are TA
designed compared to only 3% in Chicago – a city which is not just less
regulated than London (so office space is cheaper) but regulation is less
gameable because Chicago is a rule-based zoning system, rather than the
more political development control process we use in Britain.
The deadweight loss associated with this way of
gaming the planning system may be fully or partially offset because ‘Trophy
Architecture’ generates welfare for residents and tourists; or even for the
occupants of other commercial buildings. In both London and Berlin, for
example, this kind of architecture generates a lot more visual interest, asmeasured by photos shared on sites like Flickr and Picasia. The
effects are even larger for contemporary buildings like the Gherkin than for historic signature buildings. So the benefits of good modern design
may go some way to offset the calculated use of design by developers to build
bigger buildings.
*
For houses the story seems somewhat more
straightforward. People do pay for better
design, so good architecture seems to provide direct utility – otherwise the
best known architects would not be able to charge a premium for their services. This is a private
benefit and wouldn’t seem to raise issues of market failure or a case for subsidising
design.
However, there is quite persuasive evidence, from
a series of SERC studies, that there are external economic benefits from high
quality or historic residential buildings. Property prices inside conservation areas are about 5%
higher than just outside conservation areas. Given that conservation area boundaries can be quite arbitrary, and
regulatory constraints inside conservation areas are costly, this effect is
likely attributable to the special design character in these areas. This jump
in prices at the boundary is particularly large where residents report the architectural quality of the area is large relative to nearby areas. On a four-step scale (from ‘not
at all distinctive’ to ‘very distinctive’), a one-step increase is associated
with an increase in prices of up to 25%.
Interestingly, this research also
finds a positive price effect for conservation area properties that have modern
(post-WWII) design, and even for properties outside conservation areas with a
view onto buildings inside a conservation area. This is consistent with otherSERC research showing price increases in nearby areas after a conservation area
has been designated.
So we can see positive house
price effects from all kinds of ‘good architecture’. For example, residential
buildings designed by Frank Lloyd Wright – sometimes referred to as the
Greatest American Architect of all time - have a positive spillovereffect of up to 8% in Chicago’s Oak Park. The redevelopment of the Wembley stadium – designed by
trophy architects Fosters and Partners – was followed by increases in propertyprices by up to 15% in nearby areas with a view.
*
Let’s sum up. Policymakers
intervene in property markets to protect historic buildings, and to promote
‘good’ modern architecture and design quality. From an efficiency point of
view, the justification for these policies is that markets may undervalue good
architecture, because such features of buildings and neighbourhoods represent
external benefits or a form of public good.
In the UK, regulations for
historic districts or Listed Buildings can be very tight and costly: they may
control the colour of paintwork and protect internal details of layout and
design making it difficult to adapt such buildings for modern use or improve
energy efficiency to modern standards. Even where less extreme, the cost of
redevelopment behind facades is very high.
So far the evidence suggests that there are
external benefits associated with high quality residential buildings and
neighbourhoods: but the evidence is much weaker when it comes to commercial
buildings, especially given the peculiar British practice of using expensive TAs
to game the system to get more space on a given site. So where does this leave
policy?
On balance the most plausible position is that
there is a welfare economics case for public policy to support some good design
and heritage neighbourhoods, and that this case is stronger in the context of
residential than commercial buildings. But as with any policy and regulation
there are costs, here in the form of restricted supply and affordability and
rent-seeking behaviour. Most notably, these costs are particularly high in a
context where a planning system – as in Britain – makes living and working space notoriously scarce and leaves many planning decisions
the outcome of a quasi-political and bargaining approach. If there was
sufficient space for development, the external cost of preserving relatively
low density heritage areas would be less. And if decision making was
rule-governed there would be far less incentive to employ Trophy Architects
just to game the system to get more space on a given site – as opposed to
improving design quality.
Subscribe to:
Posts (Atom)